A Single Comment — Permalink
© ICCforum.com, 2010–2024. All rights reserved. Policies | Guidelines
Featured Comments
- SusanKnisely: I work with a good number complex crime victims. The population is those who are victims of terrorism and human trafficking; women, children and their families. My commentary is based on experience with these victims rather than theory. Sadly, in America, our legal system fails especially in complex cases. One reason I discovered is that many attorneys don't want to take on a complex case as they could earn the same income from a "easy," case. Second is a resistance by the private legal system... (more)
- Cowdery: It is to be hoped that the ICC, like other courts, would be able to play a crime prevention role in respect of the offences with which it deals; but a few basic points need to be made in the interests of realism. First it is not like other courts. Domestic criminal courts have jurisdiction over a geographical area covered by law enforcement officials who feed offences into those courts. There is reach, permanence and consistency of action. There is a real risk of detection and... (more)
- Kimia: Coercive Diplomacy: An ICC Approach to Minimize Human Rights Atrocities Argument Instead of focusing on a retribution approach, the ICC should think about using a coercive diplomacy framework in some cases. At a time when perpetrators have committed crimes and are able to wage ongoing human rights abuses, this approach may induce short-term deterrence. Introduction... (more)
- elio: Argument To achieve long-term deterrence and prevention of crimes, the ICC must first be seen as a legitimate and credible threat. To be seen as a credible threat, the ICC should employ two methods. First, the ICC should take a broad view of the “complementarity” principle. Second, when the ICC decides to issue an arrest warrant, it should resolutely... (more)
- Patrick S Wegner: Interesting post Jonathan. I think the idea of proactive complementarity goes into the right direction, but there are also some dangers in trying to rush domestic prosecutions. The International Crimes Division (ICD) of the Ugandan High Court would be a good example for the type of domestic prosecutions furthered by the ICC that you suggest. The Court was set up in the scope of the accountability discussions during the Juba negotiations with the Lord's Resistance Army. The need to talk about... (more)
- grant2012: ICC Should Plea-Bargain to Prevent Crime and Bring Restorative Justice to Victims Argument The International Criminal Court (ICC) should utilize plea bargaining with criminal leaders prior to trial to remove criminal leaders who enflame hostilities from their positions of power. By removing criminal leaders, the ICC can serve its mission by preventing future crimes emanating from that conflict and... (more)
- Sean.Lowe: Economic Sanctions & Capacity Building: Two Approaches to Prevent Atrocities Most Effectively Argument Because the ICC does not address crime with all of the traditional tools of punishment, it follows that the ICC must look to creative, non-traditional approaches for it to maximize its crime prevention impact. The ICC, then, should focus on two specific priorities, the first of... (more)
- nmoley: Argument The ICC’s overall effectiveness would be improved if it undertook a clear rule delineating when a state is “unwilling or unable” to prosecute on its own. In order to achieve the aims of preventing crime, promoting justice, and ending impunity for perpetrators of serious crimes, the ICC must continually legitimize itself in the eyes of the international community. At the same time, the... (more)
- jonathan.tobin: Argument The International Criminal Court can increase its legitimacy by focusing upon a strategy of complementarity. Such a strategy would mean that the ICC works closely with member states to develop and act upon agreed-upon standards of prosecution in cases of war crimes and other results of widespread violence. This strategy would also increase the visibility of the ICC such that it would not be seen as a... (more)
- davidlee211: Positive Complementarity: Prospects and Limits Argument In order to maximize its effectiveness in the prevention of crimes, the ICC should continue to encourage and assist States Parties in undertaking national prosecutions of international crimes through what is called “positive complementarity.” While there are significant obstacles to positive complementarity, there are several ways to overcome them and to... (more)
- G. L.: Argument The International Criminal Court (ICC), as an isolated legal institution, has minimal deterrent effect on the crimes it has jurisdiction over. However, it is a part of a greater trend in international law fostering universal condemnation for these crimes and thus creating an environment where such crimes are unsupportable and indefensible. I. Introduction The preamble of the... (more)
- Scott McDonald: Argument In order for OTP to maximize its prevention of crime, it must base its policies on a cost-benefit model of deterrence. This model advances the idea that an actor will stop (or not begin) rights violating behavior when the cost of that behavior outweighs its benefits. There are different classes of actors that the ICC must work towards deterring however, and each class has different considerations that play... (more)
- danterzian: Professor Goldstone praises the ICC as the world's best hope for preventing crimes against humanity. But it's just that: A hope. He argues that the key to achieving justice and preventing crimes is universal ratification of the Rome Statute. I disagree. Signatories aren't the key; soldiers are. The Democratic Republic of Congo, for example, signed the Rome Statute. And the ICC indicted Congolese General Bosco Ntaganda. Yet he lives openly, luxuriously and lawlessly. (http://motherjones.com/... (more)
- Scott McDonald: I agree with Mr. Goldstone that the emerging doctrine of Responsibility to Protect (R2P) represents a key opportunity for the ICC to maximize its crime prevention capabilities. However, its usefulness seems limited by the recently defined crime of aggression, which allows for force only in the traditional cases of self-defense or U.N.S.C. authorization. While the U.N.S.C. is to be applauded for utilizing an R2P rationale for the first time following the limited adoption of the doctrine at the... (more)
- Alma Pekmezovic: Introduction The ICC has been established with jurisdiction over various types of crimes, including: genocide, war crimes and crimes against humanity. These crimes affect “international peace and security.”1 The main purpose of the Court is to end impunity for these crimes and bring individuals who have committed such crimes to justice.2 At the most basic level, the function of the ICC is to... (more)
- Cecilia: Argument The International Criminal Court should actively employ positive complementarity and defer to non-prosecutorial methods when appropriate in preventing crime. Deterring crime involves more than prosecution by the ICC. Changing societal norms and standards through positive complementarity and alternative justice mechanisms may have a long-term preventative impact. Introduction If the ICC... (more)
- danterzian: Argument The ICC’s threat of punishment, while disincentivizing prospective criminals from committing crimes, ineffectively disincentives current criminals from committing further crimes. Thus, if the ICC wishes to prevent crimes in ongoing conflicts, it should employ practices beyond threatening punishment such as pre-arrest plea bargaining. Introduction Threatening punishment deters... (more)
Comment on the Prevention Question: “What measures should be taken to maximize the crime prevention impact of the International Criminal Court?”
Economic Sanctions & Capacity Building: Two Approaches to Prevent Atrocities Most Effectively
Argument
Because the ICC does not address crime with all of the traditional tools of punishment, it follows that the ICC must look to creative, non-traditional approaches for it to maximize its crime prevention impact. The ICC, then, should focus on two specific priorities, the first of which it have little or no role in effectuating: first, and most importantly, the international community must impose significant, personal economic sanctions on those defendants evading ICC arrest warrants (with the most effective deterrent expected upon other potential violators); and second, it needs to provide useful support to national judicial institutions.
I. Introduction
Sometimes forgotten or lost in the discourse revolving around the efficacy of the International Criminal Court (“ICC”) is the uniqueness that defines the institutional capabilities of the ICC itself. Unlike traditional courts of a sovereign country, the ICC has narrowly proscribed abilities to accomplish daunting tasks that its member countries have, effectively, foisted upon it with quite ambitious treaty language.1 Directly following one of its fundamental aspirations, the punishment of heinous human rights violations,2 it expressly affirms the importance of preventing this outrageous conduct.3
To accomplish that particular purpose, though, the ICC lacks some of the basic tools that typical courts possess: including the ability to issue an order that a responsive law enforcement agency or security apparatus will carry out.4 Additionally, even as every criminal court must justify its jurisdiction over the accused, the ICC has a particularly intricate jurisdiction and admissibility framework for determining the appropriateness of the ICC as a forum in every case.5 The Chief Prosecutor must also show that both the crime and the criminal rise to a sufficient level of importance that justifies ICC involvement, inter alia.6 All of these characteristics distinguish the ICC from a typical national criminal tribunal, and that difference must be recognized when theorizing about how to maximize, most effectively, the crime prevention impact of the ICC. Otherwise, commentators risk misdiagnosing the issue and developing a prescription in error.
Observers of the ICC also cannot forget that the ICC is a judicial institution. Not surprisingly, courts most effectively prevent crime by punishing it. Because many recognize that the ICC has not been able to try many of the people it indicts, they settle on another useful role for the ICC: assisting national judicial systems in an attempt to prevent crime. The ICC, however, remains focused on those leaders at the top of a countries’ food chain, so this paper proceeds on the assumption that assisting national judicial institutions, especially when the indicted individual remains in power, will probably not prevent currently-occurring or future crimes most effectively—or crimes sustained anywhere other than the country receiving assistance, and probably only to the subset of future crimes.7 In other words, asking the ICC to accomplish goals in that vein may bring about some useful results, but the true potential of the ICC rests in reaching verdicts—and, more specifically, in the world seeing that process conclude with a verdict.8 Achieving that end serves as my North Star, even as I will acknowledge that other efforts can attain some level of crime prevention success. Part II will explicate these two approaches in detail, before offering concluding remarks in Part III.
II. Approaches That Can Effectively Harness The ICC’s Institutional Uniqueness
A. Global Economic Sanctions that Deter Atrocities
The first, and ultimately most important strategy presented here actually requires little effort on the part of the ICC. That observation stems what I find is the most fundamentally important quality of a judicial institution: legitimacy.9 Unlike the respect that the rule of law receives in many westernized countries, the international community clearly lacks that same high esteem in regards to the mandate of the ICC.10 Consequently, the international community must properly establish the institutional respect necessary to realize, most effectively, the prevention of war crimes.11 While the ICC will serve as the greatest institutional beneficiary should the international community rally behind bringing in recipients of its arrest warrants (as it clearly has not done thus far), this approach will provide the ICC with little, if any, role.
With that perspective in mind, the question becomes how can the international community support the ICC, which relies upon it to detain those individuals that it issues arrest warrants for. The answer to this inquiry, unlike many on this subject, is actually quite simple: the international community must fervently support the apprehension of all those to whom the ICC issues an arrest warrant. That conclusion begs a much more difficult, and politically fraught, inquiry: what does an international effort look like, and by what means is it nurtured, for successfully beckoning those indicted to surrender to the ICC?12
1. The Role of Economic Sanctions in Allowing ICC Trials to Proceed (and in Preventing Crime).
The ICC’s inability to bring in defendants for trial largely stands as the obstacle preventing the ICC from fully functioning within its current mandate.13 What most commentators will generally acknowledge, though, is that maximizing the crime prevention impact of the ICC, as it is currently structured, cannot be accomplished without a strong infusion of international assistance.14 Put differently, maximization of the ICC’s crime prevention impact cannot occur within anything resembling the status quo and without broad international advocacy. To bring in perpetrators and reinforce (or develop) the international norm that “crime doesn’t pay,” the ICC must rely upon international pressure. That leaves the obvious question of what type of international pressure.
Generally speaking, three forms of international pressure exist. These range from diplomacy to economic sanctions to military engagement. Relying on diplomatic pressure serves as the least costly alternative, with a full scale military invasion possessing the highest budgetary price tag. Beyond considerations of line-item expenditures, economic sanctions can cost the United States economy large amounts in the form of lost business opportunities.15 As a practical matter, then, only diplomacy serves as a low-cost option.
When diplomacy fails, as it typically does in these circumstances, an uncomfortable question remains: is trying war criminals worth the high cost associated with bringing them in? From a militaristic perspective, up to this point, that answer is almost always no. With a couple of notable exceptions, few countries willingly risk their own blood and treasure to see perpetrators of mass murder in a distant land brought to justice. In other words, while they readily issue diplomatic statements condemning such actions, they remain far less willing to go any further.
Economic sanctions, then, appear as a third way to balance costs and moral outrage. Quite significantly, this cost does not exist on the federal budget, so the political headwinds remain significantly weaker than, say, when a Prime Minister proposes military action. But, by any measure, the costs can be quite substantial to every country that participates.16 Thus the challenge: convince individual countries to join a costly march that may, in the end, accomplish little beyond causing a country to suffer while its elite continue to prosper and live in impunity. On the other hand, no one wants to stand by and watch another Rwandan massacre occur. Consequently, economic sanctions emerge time and again as an acceptable, if not preferred, response to moral outrage. Even still, how would economic sanctions operate in bolstering the ICC’s lack of legitimacy on the world stage?
In this context, economic sanctions send two particular messages in line with specific and general deterrence principles. First, if the ICC an arrest warrant for an individual for war crimes, they will have to come to The Hague or face extensive, personal economic penalties—assuming an effective sanctions regime. Second, other individuals who may consider committing these same kinds of atrocities will realize the significant penalties associated with this conduct. The aspiration is that those future perpetrators may come to view the costs of such reprehensible behavior as much too high. That, while setting a fantastically high bar, remains the goal.
Economic sanctions along these lines have a number of necessary characteristics. These descriptors will be listed below before further explication will follow.
i. Multi-lateral, with a few narrow exceptions.
The first quality serves as a general litmus test of a sanction’s effectiveness. Unless a specific country wields an inordinate amount of influence over the sanctions target, chances are that unilateral sanctions, while politically pleasing, will be economically ineffective.17 After all, how unilateral sanctions can press an elite into turning him—or her-self in to the ICC, when other global competitors stand ready to fill the gaps left by the sanctioning country’s disappearing enterprise, is unknown.18 For that reason alone, barring the special influence exception articulated previously, unilateral sanctions are discouraged.
ii. As specific as possible, focusing first on travel bans and finance freezes.
Within the economic sanctions discourse, the modifier “smart” is used to describe sanctions that seek a very particular ends while avoiding unnecessary collateral damage.19 That adjective doesn’t seem too useful here because, inter alia, it doesn’t specifically describe the means by which the sanctions act. Precise sanctions as a term, whether the targeted activity is large or small, seems to better capture this notion.
In delineating precise sanctions, the focus should begin with the kinds of sanctions that exact the lowest costs on those carrying out the sanctions. Naturally, then, these should include travel bans and freezes of financial assets.20 Travel bans offer a relatively costless, symbolic gesture that begins what will hopefully consist of a series of efforts to isolate a leader. If properly carried out, freezes of financial assets can effectively cripple a regime because unpaid foot soldiers tend not to fight willingly. Because speed and secrecy are of the utmost importance for carrying forth this prerogative, enacting these sanctions might qualify as the kind a country could, on its own, enact before seeking international support. To the extent that secrecy is no longer important, and the nation issuing unilateral sanctions does not possess an inordinate amount of influence over the sanctions target, a concerted effort should be made to proceed only with broad international support to ensure that the sanctions regime is effective.
iii. Arms embargos on large-scale and advanced weaponry.
Counter-intuitively, general arms embargos can cause more bloodshed. This occurred during the Balkans conflict when, upon a cessation of outside arms supplies to the area, the Serbs, who now solely possessed almost all of the munitions factories throughout the conflict area, immediately had a superior military position to carry out their campaign of horror.21 The massive, unintended consequences that resulted from that general arms embargo should cause one to pause before reinstituting that same kind of regime elsewhere.
Those events have not led me to conclude that arms embargos should never occur, but rather that arms embargos, unless all sides in a conflict have similar weapons inventories and production capabilities, should only be levied in regards to large-scale and advanced weaponry. While some risks remain that any embargo could tilt the playing field towards one opponent, stopping the flow of these weapons classes reaches a proper balance between legitimate arms and those that can destroy hundreds, if not thousands, of lives. And generally speaking, only advanced economies can produce many of those tools of destruction efficiently,22 so pulling them out of a conflict zone, unless one side already has a large inventory of and production capability for these weapons, will only tilt a conflict in the direction of peace.
iv. Avoid general bans on economic activities.
Beyond travel bans, asset freezes, and arms embargos, individual sovereigns and the international community have utilized a number of varying techniques in enacting economic sanctions. These include whole scale trade embargos,23 to prohibited trade with entities associated with a particular group—in one case, the Revolutionary Guard Corps of Iran.24 What is clear from history is that broad trade embargos inflict large amounts of pain on everyday citizens while the elite continues to live in relative prosperity.25 The economic suffering of everyday people creates two, significant unintended consequences. First, it allows the elite to consolidate control over the distribution of goods.26 That has important implications for the political opposition’s ability to sustain its movement. Second, and equally as significant, the scarcity of goods allows an indicted political leader to foster a siege-like mentality among the people of his or her nation.27 Both of those consequences suggests that precise sanctions are, as a general matter, superior to general trade embargos meant to persuade leaders to accept a demand.
Further, a group of people that can barley manage fulfilling the basic necessities of life may have little interest in sending their leader to the ICC while quite fixated on finding the next meal. Correspondingly, a well-nourished populace is better positioned to organize opposition.
General trade embargos also have far-reaching consequences on the trading partners of the leader targeted with sanctions. For instance, while the American oil industry lost out on lucrative opportunities in Iraq for many years, all of Iraq’s trading partners, including Turkey, sustained even greater losses at the hand of the United Nations sanctions against Iraq.28 Richard Haas has suggested that those sovereigns that sanction should also set aside a compensatory fund for third-party nations who suffer from the sanctions’ effects.29 This fund would also ensure better compliance with the sanction regime by lowering the urge to cheat.
v. Provide for suspension of sanctions given a specific exigency.
One interesting observation provided by Robin Geiss stems from the proposition that sanctions work best when the citizenry in the country of a particular leader targeted for sanctions does not actually suffer enormously at the hands of the sanctions. While some level of suffering remains inevitable, temporarily halting the sanctions if, for instance, a humanitarian situation spirals out of control, will preclude the sanctions regime from engendering significant levels of collateral damage.30
Sanctions, based upon these guidelines, have a legitimate chance at persuading a leader indicted by the ICC to change course. Clear examples from history, though, show that economic sanctions do not always work. A quintessential example of ineffective sanctions on a country is the continuing effort to convince North Korea to cease its nuclear weapons program. Even as most North Koreans live in abject poverty, Kim Jong Il, North Korea’s leader, spends a massive annual sum on expensive cognac (and many other luxuries).31 But sanctions apparently led Col. Mummar Gaddafi to give up his nuclear weapons program, paving the way for the military campaign that appears to have ousted him from leadership. Whether those same sanctions would have convinced Col. Gaddafi to show up in The Hague, though, is a far different question. What that episode does teach is that sanctions can incentivize leaders to take actions that they previously found unthinkable.32
2. Even if Leaders Won’t Surrender Pursuant to an ICC Arrest Warrant, the Sanctions Levied Have an Important General Deterrent Purpose.
Sanctions probably have their best chance of preventing crime that has not yet occurred. While leaders will probably dig in against economic sanctions with their personal freedom on the line, another leader may view those costs as too high to proceed with actions resembling war crimes. But to impose near-suffocating, personal economic costs, the international community must stand in solidarity behind these sanctions. It goes without saying that isolating a leader, which is essentially what economic sanctions accomplish, does not work if other nations fail to enforce them. In other words, the international community cannot allow justice to leak due to pure economic opportunism. While some leaders wouldn’t mind sipping Hennessey cognac in their isolated nation amidst the great suffering of their people, some leaders might not like that idea and adjust their behavior—once they saw the international community punishing it—accordingly.
B. A Role for the ICC: Useful Assistance to National Judicial Institutions
The second, far more inferior strategy for maximizing the crime prevention impact of the ICC involves coordination with signatory countries to better improve national judicial systems. This approach, largely characterized as positive complementarity,33 relies upon a variety of means to bolster a nation’s judicial system. And unlike economic sanctions, the ICC may take a direct role in carrying forth this goal.
While this seems less helpful given that the targets in these kinds of cases are equivalent to a king or prince of that nation, the International Criminal Tribunals established for Rwanda and the former Yugoslavia demonstrate how important this assistance can be. Principles of specific deterrence would also support this kind of assistance.34
Beneficial forms of ICC-led assistance could include both monetary and judicial aid. In considering monetary assistance, while focusing less on physical structures, unless critical, and focusing more on the necessary elements of a criminal prosecution, such as research materials and advocacy training, will give these nations a foundation to prosecute absent ICC assistance.35 In the meantime, loaning judges, prosecutors, and defense counsel could be useful if national leaders (and those in the legal profession) accepted these services.36 Ideally, some type of clinical education would accompany this legal assistance in the form of simulations and the like. Given the ICC’s superior, albeit limited, resources, as well as its unique platform to champion a judicial cause, it possesses the practical tools to carry forth this goal.
By choosing to channel judicial resources to a country in need, questions of implementation arise. Will civil or common law control? How long will the international footprint last? Who will fund this endeavor if the United States, as a non-signatory to the Rome Statute, offers little monetary aid? It’s also unclear whether the ICC possesses authority under the Rome Statute to spearhead these efforts.37 Perhaps they could send human resources, but passing out monetary aid seems more like a job fit for the United States Agency for International Development (“USAID”).
III. Conclusion
Clearly, inherent difficulties exist under either approach for maximizing the crime prevention impact of the ICC. Notably, under the first, foreign polices of “non-intervention” telegraph a general unwillingness to punish most types of repugnant behavior without a close nexus to a national interest. There are also rather large opportunity costs to forgoing business opportunities that sanctions foreclose. A partial solution involves transforming the issue into a poignant moral question, i.e., will country X allow more bloodshed by ignoring sanctions so its large corporations can record higher profits? NGOs certainly have a place in framing this kind of debate.
At bottom, though, persuading leaders to come in may prove impossible. Persuading future leaders to avoid the same sorts of conduct, because of the difficulty that widely-enforced sanctions will visibly impose on current indicted leaders, may prove not only possible but effective. Simultaneously, the ICC can champion improvements in national judicial systems. And by taking steps to shore up national legal systems, these actions could have the unintended consequence of improving its own legitimacy—by showing that administering justice, and not playing politics, remains its foremost priority.
Endnotes — (click the footnote reference number, or ↩ symbol, to return to location in text).
See Preamble of the Rome Statute of the International Criminal Court, Adopted by the United Nations Diplomatic Conference of Plenipotentiaries on the Establishment of an International Criminal Court, July 17 1998, UN Doc. A/CONF.183/9 [hereinafter cited as Rome Statute], (proposing “to put an end to impunity for the perpetrators of [grave] crimes,” by “[r]esolv[ing] to guarantee lasting respect for and the enforcement of international justice”). ↩
Rome Statute, supra note 1, Preamble (describing the ICC’s mandate to include “jurisdiction over the most serious crimes of concern to the international community”). ↩
Rome Statute, supra note 1, Preamble (declaring that the ICC should “contribute to the prevention of [grave] crimes”). ↩
Due to this deficiency, Author prescribes a sort of ICC snatch team as one of two ways to improve the crime prevention impact of the ICC. See David Scheffer, Maximizing Opportunities to Deter Further Atrocity Crimes, ICC Forum, Oct. 6, 2011, available online. ↩
See Rome Statute, supra note 1, art. 12, 13, & 17. ↩
See Rome Statute, supra note 1, art. 6, 7(1), & 8(1). ↩
It’s not clear how, on a general deterrence theory, future perpetrators in other countries would be deterred by judicial improvements in another sovereign. There certainly is an argument that future war crimes will be deterred in the country that receives judicial assistance. ↩
Just outcomes remain critical for fostering support for the ICC among the international community. An incorrect guilty verdict could seriously undermine the marginal support that currently exists for the ICC, even if a defendant may have been guilty of other, lesser offenses. ↩
Time and again, commentators extol the necessity of this virtue in preventing crime. See James Alexander, The International Criminal Court and the Prevention of Atrocities, 54 Vill. L. Rev. 1, 26 (2009). ↩
In an almost mechanical fashion, an ICC indictment tends to precipitate the following sequence: first, the indicted usually issues anti-western tirades before subsequently vowing to avoid the tribunal entirely. See Bashir rattled, but unbowed, BBC News, May 13, 2009, available online. In other words, these alleged perpetrators of war crimes tend to personify the definition of impunity. ↩
The ICC may be able to slowly develop the respect necessary for it to establish international legitimacy through impartial behavior. The problem here is that it does not have enough partners willing to utilize their police powers. But without another alternative, it must rely upon the unreliable international community to fill this void. See Jack Goldsmith, The Self-Defeating International Criminal Court, 70 U. Chi. L. Rev. 89, 92 (2003). ↩
Because an indictment represents the Prosecutor’s judgment that a sovereign is “unwilling or unable” to try the alleged perpetrator in question, Rome Statute, supra note 1, art. 17, a national trial is hardly an option here. ↩
Of course, the ICC could always function on a wider scale if more countries ratified the Rome Statue, but that is not to say that it cannot effectively work within the parameters that currently govern its operation. ↩
See, e.g., Payam Akhavan, Beyond Impunity: Can International Criminal Justice Prevent Future Atrocities?, 95 Am. J. Int’l L. 7, 10 (2001). ↩
See Gary Clyde Hufbauer & Barbara Oeeg, Economic Sanctions: Public Goals and Private Compensation, 4 Chi. J. Int’l L. 305, 310-11 (2003) (noting the 94-99% reductions in bilateral trade flows, as well as the loss of confidence in American suppliers “out of fear that, in the future, their US Suppliers might be caught up in a sanctions episode.”). ↩
See id. ↩
See Richard N. Haas, Sanctioning Madness, 76 Foreign Aff. 74, 77 (1997) (“Unilateral sanctions are particularly ineffective.”). ↩
See Gary Clyde Hufbauer et al., Economic Sanctions Reconsidered, 12 (2d ed. 1990). ↩
See generally Smart Sanctions: The Next Steps-The Debate on Arms Embargoes and Travel Restrictions within the Bonn-Berun Process, (Michel Brozoska ed., 2001). ↩
See Robin Geiss, Humanitarian Safeguards in Economic Sanctions Regimes: A Call for Automatic Suspension Clauses, Periodic Monitoring, and Follow-Up Assessment of Long Term Effects, 18 Harv. Hum. Rts. J. 167, 184 (2005). ↩
Paul R. Williams & Michael P. Sharf, Peace with Justice? War Crimes and Accountability in the Former Yugoslavia, 25 (2002). ↩
See T.S. Jan & C.-G. Jan, Development of Weapons Systems in Developing Countries: A Case Study of Long Range Strategies in Taiwan, 51 J. Oper. Res. Soc’y 1041, 1043 (2000). ↩
Adam Winkler, Just Sanctions, 21 Hum. Rts. Q. 133, 138 (1999). ↩
Editorial, Congress, Sanctions, and Iran, N.Y. Times, July 2, 2010, at A18. ↩
Haas, supra note 17, at 80 (“authoritarian, statist societies are often able to hunker down and withstand the effects of sanctions.”). ↩
Id. ↩
Id. (“sanctions can sometimes trigger a ‘rally around the flag’ nationalist reaction”). See also Hufbauer, supra note 18, at 12. ↩
Douglas Frantz, At Iraq’s Backdoor, Turkey Flouts Sanctions, N.Y. Times, March 30, 2001, at A1 (describing Turkish officials estimates that the sanctions had damaged Turkey’s economy to the tune of $35 billion to $40 billion). ↩
Haas, supra note 17, at 81. ↩
Geiss, supra note 20, at 186. ↩
See Elizabeth Williamson, Hitting Kim Jong Il Right in the Cognac, Wash. Post, Nov. 30, 2006, (citing an estimate putting Kim Jong Il’s “annual cognac budget at up to $800,000 a year.”). ↩
See Patrick E. Tyler, Blair Visits Qaddafi, Ending Libya’s Long Estrangement, N.Y. Times, March 26, 2004, at A3. ↩
See generally ICC, OTP, Report on Prosecutorial Strategy, at 5 (September 14, 2006) (“[T]he Office has adopted a positive approach to complementarity, meaning that it encourages national proceedings where possible; relies on national and international networks; and participates in a system of international cooperation.”). ↩
Principles of general deterrence might apply here, allow its unclear why a potential perpetrator would change course because of the ICC’s promise of judicial assistance. Presumably, they would believe themselves capable of refusing such support, thereby rending the offer an ineffective deterrent. ↩
See Norman Farrell, The Evolution of Capacity Building Through Direct Interaction: A Prosecutor’s Perspective, in Assessing the Legacy of the ICTY 177, 178-79 (Richard H. Steinberg ed., 2011). ↩
See Bakone Justice Moloto, International Facilitation of the Self-Determined Development of the Legal System of the Former Yugoslavia, in Assessing the Legacy of the ICTY 173, 174-75 (Richard H. Steinberg ed., 2011). ↩
The Rome Statute does not specify the legality of the ICC’s efforts in this regard. ↩